Non-exclusionary input prices
dc.citation.doi | 10.1080/13504851.2014.881961 | en_US |
dc.citation.epage | 732 | en_US |
dc.citation.issue | 11 | en_US |
dc.citation.jtitle | Applied Economics Letters | en_US |
dc.citation.spage | 727 | en_US |
dc.citation.volume | 21 | en_US |
dc.contributor.author | Nadimi, Soheil R. | |
dc.contributor.author | Weisman, Dennis L. | |
dc.contributor.authoreid | weisman | en_US |
dc.date.accessioned | 2014-07-22T13:37:58Z | |
dc.date.available | 2014-07-22T13:37:58Z | |
dc.date.issued | 2014-04-01 | |
dc.date.published | 2014 | en_US |
dc.description.abstract | This paper models a vertically-integrated provider that is a monopoly supplier of an input that is essential for downstream production. An input price that is “too high” can lead to inefficient foreclosure and one that is “too low” creates incentives for non-price discrimination. The range of non-exclusionary input prices is circumscribed by the input prices generated on the basis of upper-bound and lower-bound displacement ratios. The admissible range of the ratio of downstream to upstream price-cost margins is increasing in the degree of product differentiation and reduces to a single ratio in the limit as the products become perfectly homogeneous. | en_US |
dc.identifier.uri | http://hdl.handle.net/2097/18119 | |
dc.language.iso | en_US | en_US |
dc.relation.uri | http://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2014.881961 | en_US |
dc.rights | This Item is protected by copyright and/or related rights. You are free to use this Item in any way that is permitted by the copyright and related rights legislation that applies to your use. For other uses you need to obtain permission from the rights-holder(s). | en_US |
dc.rights.uri | http://rightsstatements.org/vocab/InC/1.0/ | |
dc.subject | Input prices | en_US |
dc.subject | Vertical integration | en_US |
dc.subject | Foreclosure | en_US |
dc.subject | Sabotage | en_US |
dc.title | Non-exclusionary input prices | en_US |
dc.type | Article (author version) | en_US |